Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-x24gv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-01T20:10:53.340Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Industrial Policy, Chinese-Style: FDI, Regulation, and Dreams of National Champions in the Auto Sector

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 March 2016

Extract

Long after the start of the reform period, and well after the proven success of the private sector, the fate of the state-owned sector in China continued to disturb the sleep of many policymakers in the Chinese central government.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © East Asia Institute 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Notes

My thanks to Stephan Haggard, Byung-Kook Kim, Xiaobo Lü, Andrew MacIntyre, Ito Peng, Victor Shih, Joe Wong, and the other participants in the After the Developmental State workshop for their valuable comments and assistance. Thanks also to Mary Gallagher and Scott Kennedy for comments on an earlier draft.Google Scholar

1. These figures are from Lardy, Nicholas R., China's Unfinished Economic Revolution (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institute, 1998), pp. 26 and 28.Google Scholar

2. Steinfeld, Edward S., Forging Reform in China: The Fate of State-Owned Enterprises (New York: Cambridge University, 1998), p. 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3. Lardy, , China's Unfinished Economic Revolution , p. 40. Fortunately, the locus of job creation moved away from the state sector after 1995 and toward private and foreign-invested firms. It became increasingly common for SOEs to lay off or furlough (xiagang) workers. Nevertheless, 78.8 million workers continued to be employed in the state sector in 2000, an amount virtually unchanged from two decades earlier, and the nonfinancial SOEs produced approximately one-third of China's GDP. Employment figure is from Rawski, Thomas, “Recent Developments in China's Labor Economy.” Report prepared for the International Policy Group (Geneva: International Labor Office, 2002), available at www.pitt.edu/~tgrawski/; share of GDP is from Mako, William and Zhang, Chunlin, “Exercising Ownership Rights in State Owned Enterprise Groups: What China Can Learn from International Experience,” World Bank Note (2002), available at www.worldbank.org.cn.Google Scholar

4. Naughton, Barry, Growing Out of the Plan (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995), p. 164.Google Scholar

5. Steinfeld provides excellent analysis of why small Chinese firms have difficulty moving into the higher–value-added parts of global production chains. Steinfeld, Edward S., “Chinese Enterprise Development and the Challenge of Global Integration.” In Yusuf, Shahid, ed., East Asian Networked Production (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, forthcoming).Google Scholar

6. See Qiyesi, Guojia Jingmaowei Jituanchu, Gongsi, “Guojia daxing shidian qiye jituan gaige zhuanji” [Collection of articles on trial reform of national large-scale enterprise groups], Jingji Yanjiu Cankao [Economic Research Reference] 83 (May 1995): 1116.Google Scholar

7. For an argument along these lines, see Huang, Yasheng, Selling China: Foreign Direct Investment During the Reform Era (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003), chap. 6.Google Scholar

8. The focus of the article is on the center's ability to shape the structure of industrial development, as measured by the degree of industrial concentration and manufacturing capabilities of key firms. These measures are not an indication of international competitiveness, but in a sector in which economies of scale and technology are critical they are a necessary first step.Google Scholar

9. The 2002 figure is from KPMG Transaction Services (Hong Kong), “China Automotive and Component Parts Market,” August 2003, p. 9. The 2003 figure is from “China Emerges as the World's Fourth-Largest Auto Maker,” Taiwan Economic News, April 16, 2004.Google Scholar

10. Evans, Peter, Dependent Development: The Alliance of Multinational, State, and Local Capital in Brazil (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1979).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

11. Huang, , Selling China. Huang refers to the “quintessentially” Chinese activities at numerous points and acknowledges that foreign firms in technology- and capital-intensive sectors will have obvious advantages but argues that this is a relatively small portion of FDI (pp. 12). The bulk of the argument abandons these distinctions between types of FDI, and Huang argues that such specification is not necessary because FDI dominates across the boards. In fact, the automotive sector becomes a core piece of the argument. The problem with this lack of specification is that readers can easily come away with the conclusion that FDI is preventing Chinese firms from dominating critical aspects of the Chinese economy (the “pillar” industries such as autos) when Huang is essentially arguing that there are private firms in labor-intensive and traditional Chinese industries (lower–value-added activities) that would be able to more effectively compete with foreign firms if it were not for the institutional discrimination against private firms in China. Although it is certainly true that the Chinese system is biased against private firms, this is hardly an unusual argument.Google Scholar

12. Gerschenkron, Alexander, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, MA: Belknap, 1962).Google Scholar

13. Amsden, Alice H., Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrilization (Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press, 1989), p. 143.Google Scholar

14. For representative articles on the “lessons” of the Korean and Japanese experiences, see Chen, Bingcai, “Hanguo da qiye jituan de tezheng ji zhengyi” [The characteristics and debates over Korean large corporate groups], Jingji Yanjiu Cankao [Economic Research Reference] 58, no. 858 (April 12, 1996): 3438; Huan, Guoyu, “Han, re liang guo jingji gaosu cengzhang shiqi hongguan jingji guanli de jingyan qishi” [The macroeconomic management experience from the high growth economies of Korea and Japan], Jingji Gongzuozhe Xuexi Ziliao [Economic Worker Study Materials] 30–31 (April 1996): 65–78.Google Scholar

15. Vice Premier Wu Banguo offered one version of this view in 1998: “In reality, international economic confrontations show that if a country has large companies or groups it will be assured of maintaining a certain market share and a position in the international economic order. America, for example, relies on General Motors, Boeing, Dupont and a batch of other multinational companies. Japan relies on six large enterprise groups and Korea relies on ten commercial groupings. In the same way now and in the next century our nation's position in the international economic order will be to a large extent determined by the position of our nation's large enterprises and groups.” Cited in Nolan, Peter, China and the Global Economy: National Champions, Industrial Policy, and the Big Business Revolution (New York: Palgrave, 2001), p. 17.Google Scholar

16. For a summary of the symposium organized by the Ministry of Machinery in 1994, see Ministry of Machinery, “Yantaohui zongshu” [Symposium summary], Dangdai zhongguo guoji jiaoche gongye fazhan yu zhongguo jiaoche gongye fazhan zhanlue [The development of the contemporary Chinese international auto sedan industry and the Chinese auto sedan development strategy] (Beijing: Ministry of Machinery, 1994), p. 11. As a representative of the Korea Auto Industry Association pointed out: “There is no doubt that over the long-term, the support and nurturing of the government absolutely had an impact on [Korean] auto industry development. The government formulated a policy which managed the industrial system in a manner designed to prevent chaotic production.” Google Scholar

17. See, for instance, Chen, , “Hanguo da qiye jituan de tezheng ji zhengyi,” pp. 3438.Google Scholar

18. Through “preferential policies” and “government financial support” the government's intent was “to increase the competitiveness of Chinese industry in the globalized market,” commented one observer. Jing, Fu, “Colossal SOEs to Advance WTO Role,” China Daily , December 8–9, 2001, p. 1, cited in Rawski, Thomas, “Recent Developments in China's Labor Economy.” Report prepared for the International Policy Group, International Labor Office, Geneva (2002), p. 23. Available at www.pitt.edu/~tgrawski.Google Scholar

19. Perkins, Dwight H., “Industrial and Financial Policy in China and Vietnam: A New Model or a Replay of the East Asian Experience?” In Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Yusef, Shahid, eds., Rethinking the East Asia Miracle (Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press, 2001), p. 256. Rawski, , “Recent Developments in China's Labor Economy,” p. 23. China Economic Quarterly 7, no. 3 (2003): 20.Google Scholar

20. China Economic Quarterly 7, no. 3 (2003): 20.Google Scholar

21. This is the total production volumes of all vehicles, and only 2,640 of these were sedans. Ministry of Machinery, Dangdai zhongguo guoji jiaoche gongye fazhan yu zhongguo jiaoche gongye fazhan zhanlue [The development of the contemporary Chinese international auto sedan industry and the Chinese auto sedan development strategy] (Beijing: Ministry of Machinery, 1994), pp. 63 and 73.Google Scholar

22. Iwagaki, Makoto, “The State of China's Automobile Industry,” JETRO, China Newsletter , no. 63 (1986): 11.Google Scholar

23. Guojia fazhan he gaige weiyuanhui, “Qiche gongye fazhan zhengce” [Auto Industry Development Policy]. May 21, 2004.Google Scholar

24. Mackintosh, James and McGregor, Richard, “A Leap Over the Cliff,” Financial Times , August 25, 2003, p. 15.Google Scholar

25. Lindblom, Charles E., Politics and Markets: The World's Political-Economic Systems (New York: Basic Books, 1977), chap. 5.Google Scholar

26. Yang, Dali, Remaking the Chinese Leviathan: Market Transition and the Politics of Governance in China (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, forthcoming), p. 7.Google Scholar

27. Yang, , Remaking the Chinese Leviathan , p. 8.Google Scholar

28. See, for instance, Nee, Victor, “Organizational Dynamics of Market Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and Mixed Economy in China,” Administrative Science Quarterly 37 (March 1992): 127; Oi, Jean C., Rural China Takes Off: Institutional Foundations of Economic Reform (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1999); Blecher, Marc and Shue, Vivienne, Tethered Deer: Government in a Chinese County (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1996); Duckett, Jane, The Entrepreneurial State in China (London: Routledge, 1998); Thun, Eric, Changing Lanes in China: Foreign Direct Investment, Local Governments, and Auto Sector Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

29. Wang, Shaoguang and Angang, Hu, The Chinese Economy in Crisis: State Capacity and Tax Reform (Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharp, 2001); Lu, Xiaobo, “Booty Socialism, Bureau-preneurs, and the State in Transition: Organizational Corruption in China,” Comparative Politics (April 2000); Wedeman, Andrew, From Mao to Market: Local Protectionism, Rent-Seeking, and the Marketization of China, 1984–1992 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003).Google Scholar

30. Pearson, Margaret M., “Mapping the Rise of China's Regulatory State: Economic Regulation and Network and Insurance Industries.” Paper prepared for the annual meeting of the Association of Asian Studies, New York, March 27, 2003; Yang, , Remaking the Chinese Leviathan. Google Scholar

31. Shirk, Susan L., The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993), p. 149. See also Oksenberg, Michel and Tong, James, “The Evolution of Central-Provincial Fiscal Relations in China, 1971–1984: The Formal System,” China Quarterly 125 (March 1991); and Tong, James, “Fiscal Reform, Elite Turnover and Central-Provincial Relations in Post-Mao China,” Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 22 (July 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

32. Oi, , Rural China Takes Off, p. 103. The degree of autonomy varied both regionally (some cities had more autonomy than others) and over time (the central government would periodically reassert control). On varying degrees of autonomy, see Kleinberg, Robert, China's “Opening” to the Outside World: The Experiment with Foreign Capitalism (Boulder: Westview, 1990), p. 183; for the cyclical nature of the Beijing's policy, see Howell, Jude, China Opens Its Doors: The Politics of Economic Transition (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1993).Google Scholar

33. This situation was exacerbated by the tax reforms of 1994—the objective of which was to solidify the central government revenue—because the share of official budgetary revenue retained by the localities declined, but local expenditures did not. Zhang, Le-Yin, “Chinese Central-Provincial Fiscal Relationships, Budgetary Decline, and the Impact of the 1994 Fiscal Reform: An Evaluation,” The China Quarterly 157 (March 1999): 134135.Google Scholar

34. This idealized version is described in the concept of market-preserving federalism. Gabriella Montinola, Yingyi Qian, and Barry R. Weingast, “Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political Basis for Economic Successes in China,” World Politics 48 (October 1995): 5081.Google Scholar

35. On the barriers to trade see Wedeman, , From Mao to Market ; on the barriers to investment see Huang, , Selling China, chap. 6.Google Scholar

36. For details of this case, see Thun, , Changing Lanes in China. Google Scholar

37. According to some scholars, the quantity of nonbudgetary funds available to local government in China during the 1990s was often considerably more than twice the quantity of the official budget. For careful explanation of the how nonbudgetary funds are defined, collected, and utilized, see Zhang, , “Chinese Central,” p. 126.Google Scholar

38. For examples of regional blockades, see Li, Youping, “Current Regional Blockades and Suggested Solution,” Chinese Economic Studies 26, no. 5 (Fall 1993): 38. To give one indication of how internal trade barriers affect the domestic market, interprovincial trade fell from 37 percent of national retail trade in 1985 to about 25 percent in 2000: Stoyan Tenev and Chunlin Zhang with Loup Brefort, Corporate Governance and Enterprise Reform in China: Building the Institutions of Modern Markets (Washington, D.C.: World Bank and International Finance Corporation, 2002), p. 21.Google Scholar

39. Huang, , Selling China , p. 115. Typically it is believed that 250,000 units is the minimum economy of scale for an auto plant. The average production volume for the industry as whole in China was about 14,165 units.Google Scholar

40. Between 1986 and 1992, the savings rate was approximately 36 percent, and between 1994 and 1997 it increased to 42 percent; Huang, , Selling China , p. 45. As Huang notes, only Singapore had a higher savings rate. Savings rate is defined as the difference between GDP and final consumption divided by GDP and Huang's data is from the Chinese State Statistical Bureau.Google Scholar

41. On the relationship between SOEs and the financial sector, see Steinfeld, , Forging Reform in China. On the financial sectors systematic discrimination against competitive private sector firms, see Huang, , Selling China. Google Scholar

42. Even if the central government had been able to direct resources at selected sectors, this would have been problematic given that the overall purpose of reforms was to move away from government planning and toward a market economy. As an official in the State Planning Commission's Department of Long-Term Planning and Industrial Policy commented with respect to the 1994 industrial policy plans, “Not only did the central government not have the financial resources, but the general desire to move towards a market-based system, made an old-style industrial policy very difficult.” After much debate, he commented, the central government (despite the dissension of many line ministries) began in 1995 to move away from an industry-specific approach and toward a functional approach. Interview, no. B12, April 25, 1997.Google Scholar

43. Huang, , for instance, points to the acquisition strategy of FAW as support for his economic fragmentation thesis. Huang, , Selling China , p. 273.Google Scholar

44. Marukawa, Tomoo, “WTO, Industrial Policy and China's Industrial Development.” In Yamazawa, Ippei and Imai, Ken-ichi, eds., China Enters the WTO: Pursuing Symbiosis with the Global Economy (Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economies, 2001), pp. 3637.Google Scholar

45. Tianjin Automotive Xiali Company, which had formed a JV with Toyota in 2000, was taken over by FAW in 2002. “Toyota Inks Tie-Up with FAW group,” Nikkei Weekly , September 2, 2002.Google Scholar

46. When the Chery Automotive Company of Anhui Province emerged as a rapidly growing player in 2000, the center would not grant it a license to sell outside of Anhui until SAIC bought a 20 percent stake in the firm, thereby enabling the Chery to be sold under the SAIC license in other provinces (these ties were severed in 2004 when Chery was accused of stealing the designs of General Motors). “Chery Sedan Ready to Drive in Chinese New Year,” ChinaOnline , January 22, 2001 (accessed April 4, 2003); “SAIC Severs Links with Chery,” Financial Times, June 14, 2004. Similarly, after Honda formed a JV with the local government in Guangzhou, the center directed Honda to create an engine JV with Dongfeng.Google Scholar

47. This is particularly true in the case of FAW but far from unusual elsewhere. In 1997, for instance, SAIC took over two local television manufacturers in Shanghai. At the time “analysts said the decision to bring [SAIC] into the picture was part of a radical play by the municipal government to get powerful unlisted state-owned enterprises to rescue badly-run companies from bankruptcy.” Peng, Foo Choy, “SAIC Joins Bailout Group,” South China Morning Post , March 14, 1997, p. 5.Google Scholar

48. “First Auto Works Unhappy, Unwilling to Absorb Tianjin Auto,” ChinaOnline , April 15, 2002 (accessed September 22, 2002).Google Scholar

49. Steinfeld, , Forging Reform in China , p. 40.Google Scholar

50. An effective system is complex and multifaceted: an independent board of directors monitors and supervises managers; managerial labor markets align the interests of management and shareholders through the use of bonuses and/or stock options; capital markets force management to be concerned with the terms on which capital will be provided to the firm; high levels of transparency and auditing standards provide the information necessary to evaluate firm performance; and competitive markets serve as the ultimate constraint on poor performance. Prowse, Stephen, “Corporate Governance in International Perspective: A Survey of Corporate Control Mechanisms Among Large Firms in the U.S., U.K., Japan, and Germany,” Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments 4, no. 1 (February 1995): 6.Google Scholar

51. Mar, Pamela and Young, Michael N., “Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: A Case Study of Two Chinese Airlines,” Journal of World Business 36, no. 3 (Fall 2001): 282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

52. Steinfeld, , Forging Reform in China. Google Scholar

53. The primary assembly plant in Shanghai, a JV between SAIC and Volkswagen, dominated the domestic marketplace—often its market share for sedans hovered around 50 percent—and the business group as a whole was immensely profitable. For additional indicators of Shanghai's success during this period, see Thun, , Changing Lanes in China. Google Scholar

54. Interview, no. S16, May 27, 1997. In 1995, as part of an effort to make SAIC appear to be independent of government influence, this linkage was eliminated.Google Scholar

55. The career path of the current chairman of the SAIC group, Chen Xianglin, is a good example of how the leaders of the industry were shuffled through high-level positions in the municipal government. He was president of SAIC from 1983 to 1986; director of the Shanghai Planning Commission from 1987 to 1993, vice secretary of the Shanghai branch of the Chinese Communist Party from 1993 to 1994; and finally director of the Shanghai foreign trade office from 1994 to 1995. In 1995, Chen again became SAIC president (replacing Lu Jian, who in turn, returned to the Shanghai Municipal Economic Committee as vice director) and then chairman of the board in 1999. Interview, no. S16, May 27, 1997, and Interview S26, June 11, 1998.Google Scholar

56. Firms within the group inevitably had excess labor; and in stark contrast to Western firms that are trying to cut costs, they did everything possible to avoid downsizing. In some cases, expansion efforts were driven by the need to soak up excess labor.Google Scholar

57. Interview, no. S21, June 18, 1998.Google Scholar

58. Interview, no. S25, June 17, 1998.Google Scholar

59. On this point, see Steinfeld, , “Chinese Enterprise Development.” Google Scholar

60. For work on international production networks, see Borrus, Michael, Ernst, Dieter, and Haggard, Stephan, International Production Networks in Asia: Rivalry or Riches? (London and New York: Routledge, 2000).Google Scholar

61. Veloso, Francisco, “The Automotive Supply Chain Organization: Global Trends and Perspectives.” Working Paper (Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology): 6. Improvements are driven by consumer demands, increasingly stringent safety and environmental regulations, and the availability of new technologies.Google Scholar

62. The number of different vehicle models offered for sale in the United States alone doubled between 1980 and 1999, a period in which demand was essentially flat. Veloso, , “The Automotive Supply Chain Organization,” p. 5.Google Scholar

63. Although outsourcing in the auto industry is perhaps not as dramatic as in the computer industry, it is not out of the question that the larger of these global suppliers could some day serve as contract manufacturers, producing whole vehicles that are then sold under a particular brand. In some locations, this extreme of contract manufacturing has almost been achieved. VW, for instance, has been using a modular consortium approach in its Resende, Brazil, plant. It plays a strategic role in design and commercialization, but all of the actual manufacturing and assembly is done by suppliers. See Lung, Yannick, “Flexibility Through Modularity: Experimentation with Fractal Production in Brazil and in Europe.” In Lung, Yannick, Chanaron, Jean-Jacques, Fujimoto, Takahiro, and Raff, Daniel, eds., Coping with Variety: Flexible Productive Systems for Product Variety in the Auto Industry (Aldershot, U.K.: Ashgate, 1999).Google Scholar

64. Ford owns Jaguar, Volvo, Land Rover, and Aston Martin; General Motors owns Saab and significant chunks of Suzuki, Isuzu, Subaru, Fiat, and Daewoo; Toyota controls Daihatsu; Renault controls Nissan. Kenney, Martin, “Merger Activity in the Global Economy: Implications for Korea.” Paper prepared for the conference “Industrial Globalization: East Asia's Strategic Importance and the Role of Korea,” Honolulu, Hawaii, August 1999.Google Scholar

65. In the same year there were only thirteen firms with annual production volumes over 1 million, and these thirteen accounted for 87.4 percent of global production. Humphrey, John and Memedovic, Olga, The Global Automotive Value Chain (Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development Organization, 2003), p. 6.Google Scholar

66. Humphrey, and Memedovic, , The Global Automotive Value Chain. Google Scholar

67. The dominant car in the domestic market during the 1990s—SVW's Santana—was based on technology that was three decades old. A 1996 report on the overall competitiveness of the Chinese auto industry, commissioned by the Development Research Center of China's State Council, concluded that the technology of domestically manufactured cars was a minimum of five to fifteen years behind international standards, and this was undoubtedly a generous assessment. Long, Guoqiang, “Zhongguo Jiaoche Gongye Guoji Jingzhengli Fenxi” [Analysis of the international competitiveness of the Chinese auto sedan industry]. Development Research Centre of the State Council, PRC, Research Report no. 92, August 9, 1996. Long, Guoqiang, “Jinkou Guanshui Dui Zhongguo Jiaoche Gongye De Yingxiang” [The impact of import tariffs on the Chinese auto sedan industry]. Development Research Centre of the State Council, PRC, Research Report no. 93, August 9, 1996.Google Scholar

68. Interview, no. S7, May 22, 1997.Google Scholar

69. These figures are for realized FDI. Cassidy, John F., Japanese Direct Investment in China: Locational Determinants and Characteristics (New York and London: Routledge, 2002), p. 42.Google Scholar

70. Yang, Dali and Su, Fubing, “China and the Forces of Globalization.” In Prakash, Aseem and Hart, Jeffrey A., eds., Responding to Globalization (London and New York: Routledge, 2000), p. 35. Since 1997, foreign-invested firms have continued to generate approximately half of Chinese exports.Google Scholar

71. China attracted U.S.$52.7 billion in FDI in 2002. Cartledge, Simon, “The Other Side of China's Success,” Financial Times , January 20, 2003, p. 11.Google Scholar

72. Between 1990 and 1997, for example, 53.1 percent of FDI in China was from Hong Kong and 8.5 percent was from Taiwan. Cassidy, John F., Japanese Direct Investment , p. 53.Google Scholar

73. Yang calls this “competitive liberalization.” Yang, Dali, Calamity and Reform in China (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1996).Google Scholar

74. On the different phases of the FDI regime, see Sun, Haishun, Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China: 1979–1996 (Aldershot, U.K.: Ashgate, 1998), pp. 1317.Google Scholar

75. As Joe Studwell argues, the sales pitch for companies such as these has been the same for centuries: “The prospect of adding one quarter of the world's population to a corporation's list of potential clients in a single move, the prospect of a market with the statistical potential to become the biggest in the world.” Studwell, Joe, The China Dream: The Elusive Quest for the Greatest Untapped Market on Earth (London: Profile Books, 2002), p. xi.Google Scholar

76. Although Bennett and Sharpe argue that market size and growth was a source of host country bargaining leverage in Latin America, Doner did not find a correlation between market size and the intensity of inter-MNC competition in Southeast Asia. Doner, Richard F., Driving a Bargain: Automobile Industrialization and Japanese Firms in Southeast Asia (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991), p. 92. As Studwell argues, however, the potential of the China market has tended to blur the vision of MNC executives, and in many cases this clearly translated into bargaining leverage. Studwell, The China Dream. Google Scholar

77. See Norton, Patrick M. and Chao, Howard, “Mergers and Acquisitions in China,” China Business Review , September–October (2001). The catalogue is updated on a regular basis and has become increasingly liberal.Google Scholar

78. For a general discussion of the governmental role in the choice of JV partners and the formulation of performance, local content, and technology transfer requirements, see Rosen, Daniel H., Behind the Open Door: Foreign Enterprises in the Chinese Marketplace (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economies, 1999), chap. 2.Google Scholar

79. See Yang, Dali and Su, Fubing, “China and the Forces of Globalization.” In Prakash, and Hart, , Responding to Globalization , pp. 4547.Google Scholar

80. The most recent example of utilizing standards to impose what critics called a nontariff barrier was the wireless standard that the Chinese government announced but then abandoned in April 2003.Google Scholar

81. First Auto is partnered with VW and Toyota (in Tianjin); Dongfeng is partnered with Citroen and Nissan (in Guangdong); Shanghai is partnered with VW and GM.Google Scholar

82. On the Chinese side, the chief negotiating party was SAIC, but it had to get multiple approvals at the central level. Often, according to negotiators on the GM side, the local government would play “good cop” to the central government's “bad cop.” Even after they were engaged in exclusive negotiations, the GM side spoke of the “Ford shadow,” a reference to the fear that if GM did not give the Chinese what they wanted, the Chinese would renew negotiations with Ford. Interview, no. S11, May 31, 1997.Google Scholar

83. SAIC wanted not only the general spec drawings of the models that would be produced in Shanghai, it wanted online access to the databases of GM's technology development center in the United States, and it wanted Computer Assisted Design (CAD) capability in a new technical development center in Shanghai. Although people involved in the negotiations were not specific with respect to the final terms of technology transfer, they would comment that GM “could not have gone much further.” Interview, no. S11, May 31, 1997.Google Scholar

84. “VW to Invest Another US $2.2 Billion in China,” ChinaOnline , December 12, 2001 (accessed September 22, 2002).Google Scholar

85. One manager used blueprints as an example of the technical shortcomings of local firms. VW did all of its design work in Germany, then simplified the blueprints before giving them to Chinese supply firms. When GM came to Shanghai they found that supply firms were simply not capable of handling the complexity of the designs that they were given. Interview, no. S34, June 30, 2000.Google Scholar

86. Interview, no. S52, January 21, 2003.Google Scholar

87. Like many SAIC suppliers, the firm had large cash reserves from a decade of highly profitable SVW business and could have financed this upgrading internally. Because the nature of the investment qualified as high-tech, the JV was able to receive no-interest loans from the national government. The JV took the loans, banked its own money, and paid off the loans as soon as they were due.Google Scholar

88. Interview, no. S42, July 13, 2000.Google Scholar

89. Huang, , Selling China , pp. 282284.Google Scholar

90. Huang, , Selling China , p. 281.Google Scholar

91. In 2002, SAIC bought a 10 percent stake in the General Motors–Daewoo joint venture at a cost of U.S.$59.7 million. “Chinese Automaker Invests in GM-Daewoo Joint Venture,” Asia Pulse , October 14 October 14, 2002.Google Scholar

92. The top manufacturer of transmissions in China wanted to license technology from VW for the automatic transmissions that would be used in newer models—the central government wanted it to remain independent—but VW refused. As competition increased, however, views changed, and it was granted approval for a JV. Interview, no. S48, August 16, 2002.Google Scholar

93. Interview, no. S44, August 7, 2002. The firms that remained 100 percent SOE manufactured relatively minor parts such as springs. In many respects, what is surprising is not that these supply firms were JVs rather than Chinese-owned firms but that they were not wholly foreign-owned (an option that was open to supply firms but not assemblers). Although foreign firms increasingly preferred wholly owned ventures, auto supply firms needed the Chinese partner because this partner controlled purchasing at the assembly plant. The high presence of JVs, in other words, was an indication of continued Chinese leverage.Google Scholar

94. Guojia fazhan he gaige weiyuanhui (2004).Google Scholar

95. Mackintosh, James and McGregor, Richard, “A Leap Over the Cliff,” p. 15; Zhengzheng, Gong, “Release of New Auto Policy ‘Within Days,’” China Daily, May 28, 2004; Guojia fazhan he gaige weiyuanhui (2004).Google Scholar

96. World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy (Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press, 1993), p. 11.Google Scholar

97. As a vice director of the Shanghai Asset Management Office commented, this probably should not be surprising: “If 90 percent of your people are in JVs their thinking begins to change; all those people are working in a Western system.” Interview, no. S47, August 14, 2002.Google Scholar

98. This account of SGM purchasing is based primarily on Interview, no. S43, August 6, 2002; and Interview, no. S53, August 14, 2002. It was corroborated at supply firms throughout the SAIC group.Google Scholar

99. Firms closely guard the purchasing prices for components but in interviews would speak generally about relative prices. This assessment is based on interviews with four purchasing managers at the Shanghai assembly plants and interviews at nine Shanghai supply firms between 2000 and 2003.Google Scholar

100. In one case, a supply firm was selling a component to SGM at a loss because it was forced to meet the GM worldwide purchasing price but was unable to achieve the economies of scale that would make it profitable to do so. It was willing to do this in the short term in order to secure the contract. Interview, no. S42, July 13, 2000.Google Scholar

101. In a clear sign that it was no longer taking the China operations for granted, VW announced in 2001 that it would invest U.S.$1.45 billion in China over five years (essentially matching the GM investment). “Volkswagen to Invest US $1.45B in China in Next 5 Years,” ChinaOnline , July 13, 2001 (accessed September 22, 2002).Google Scholar

102. For more on the broader structural changes that have taken place, see Thun, , Changing Lanes in China. Shanghai has been a leading example of efforts to separate the commercial and governmental role of the state by placing firms under the control of independent asset management offices. The result is a three-tiered structure that varies slightly by region: at the top is an asset management office, in the middle are holding companies and enterprise groups (many of which were formerly line ministries), and at the bottom are the manufacturing firms. See World Bank, China's Management of Enterprise Assets: The State as Shareholder (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1997), chap. 3. In the case of SAIC, for instance, a board of directors was created in 1999 to link the first tier of asset management, the Shanghai Municipal Asset Management Office (Shanghai Shi Guoyou Zichan Guanli Bangongshi), with the second tier—the head office of the SAIC business group. Relations between the second tier and the third (the firms) are now completely characterized by the equity share that SAIC owns in any respective firm, much as if it is a holding company with a stake in different companies. The intent seems to be to create the structures of formal corporate governance, even if they are largely window dressing at this point, so as to create the possibility of a public listing and the eventual participation of more effective minority shareholders.Google Scholar

103. Steinfeld, , “Chinese Enterprise Development,” pp. 4748.Google Scholar

104. Whereas in 1980 FDI inflows formed 11.7 percent of gross domestic capital formation in manufacturing in developing countries, this number had increased to 36.7 percent by 1998. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, World Investment Report 2000: Cross-Border Mergers and Acquisitions and Development (New York: UN, 2000), p. 5.Google Scholar

105. As Steinfeld points out, the leading competitor for a Chinese computer company such as Legend is IBM, a business services and software company. Steinfeld, , “Chinese Enterprise Development,” p. 49.Google Scholar

106. For a similar argument with respect to FDI and labor, see Gallagher, Mary, “‘Reform and Openness’: Why China's Economic Reforms Have Delayed Democracy,” World Politics (April 2002).Google Scholar

107. Although JVs accounted for less than 6 percent of domestic automakers in China in 2001, they accounted for 60 percent of the profits. Chen Jianguo, an official at the State Development Planning Commission, hinted in 2001 that dozens of new JVs might be approved over the course of the next decade. Zhengzheng, Gong, “Auto Sector to Allow More Joint Ventures,” FT Asia Intelligence Wire , June 13, 2001.Google Scholar

108. This local variation is fully explained in Thun, , Changing Lanes in China. Google Scholar

109. Interview, no. B42, July 30, 2002.Google Scholar

110. Interview, no. B44, January 10, 2003. When Hyundai created a new JV in Beijing, it brought along its Korean suppliers.Google Scholar

111. Interview, no. S54, July 15, 2004.Google Scholar

112. Since the formation of the JV in 1994, the average annual return on the original investment has been 43 percent, and it has used the profits from the Santana business to expand and gain new capabilities. It generated RMB700 million in consolidated revenue in 2002. Beginning in 2000, despite rapid reinvestment of profits, the JV began to pay out dividends to its two shareholders (SAIC and the foreign firm). For the first two years each partner received RMB50 million, in 2002 the dividend was RMB150 million each, and it was expected be higher in 2003. In that the original investment of the foreign partner (U.S.$25 million) has been returned at this point, the firm is a pure profit center. Interview, no. S52, Janaury 21, 2003.Google Scholar

113. In 2001, the design center at the firm consisted of eleven people; this increased to forty-four the next year, seventy to seventy-five the next, and was expected to reach 150 by 2005. Interestingly, due to the subsidiary JVs that have been created, the Shanghai firm has a broader range of capabilities than the global supplier with which it is partnered.Google Scholar

114. The JV has skilled engineers, commented a foreign manager, but foreign participation is still necessary for any sophisticated design work. Interview, no. S45, August 8, 2002.Google Scholar